A.   Introduction: If you can’t beat Bitcoin, join ‘em?

With the rising interest in and usage of private digital currencies (e.g. Bitcoin), a policy question that has arisen is whether central banks should consider issuing official digital currencies (central bank digital currency, CBDC[1]). Consequently, research has been initiated globally to evaluate the costs and benefits of the issuance of CBDCs to the functioning of the economy, and its implications on the central bank mandates of monetary and financial stability and most directly, currency issuance and payment systems. This article reviews the current thinking on the potential impact of issuing CBDC to the conduct of monetary policy[2].

B.   Definition: What is CBDC?

CBDC, in essence, is central bank cash (banknotes and coins) made available in electronic form. Yet, “digital currency” is not new as most central bank money is already “digital”. All commercial bank deposits or reserves with the central bank represent digital claims (monetary value stored electronically). In the current setup, only member banks have access to central bank money and related payment systems such as Real-time Electronic Transfer of Funds and Securities System (RENTAS) in the case of Malaysia.

Therefore, the key innovation with CBDC is the potential for non-banks (individuals and firms) to hold direct accounts with the central banks or to transact directly with one another using the CBDC as a legal tender. This has been made possible by the   technology used in private digital currencies, namely the distributed ledger technology (DLT)[3].

Given the proposed underlying DLT, CBDCs could be thought of as a “government cryptocurrency”. However, it should be distinguished from e-money, which is merely a payment system innovation enabling cashless transactions. The key features of these forms of payment are in Table 1.

Table 1

C.   Central Bank Initiatives on CBDC (Diagram 1)

Central banks have shown varying levels of interest and progress in CBDC, with different motivations. Where the US, Sweden, China and Ecuador are interested in the CBDC for day-to-day transactions by the public, experimentations in Canada and Singapore are focused on improving the efficiency of wholesale payments and settlements system.

There has also been mixed sentiments with regards to the applicability and reliability of CBDC. Bank of Canada staff research cautions central banks to proceed carefully given operational complexities and uncertainties of retail CBDC. Moreover, Bank of Canada, Bank of England and Sveriges Riksbank have communicated the need for multi-year research before making a decision on issuing CBDC. Similarly, European Central Bank’s (ECB) senior officials have treaded with a guarded stance, posing both the merits and dangers of central banks progressing either too expeditiously or adapting too slowly given rapid technological changes.

Diagram 1

D.   What would CBDC look like? (Diagram 2)

While the CBDC would be underpinned by the use of DLT, researchers have proposed different frameworks for how CBDC could be implemented. One key consideration is the verification of transactions.

In one framework resembling private digital currencies, CBDC would involve “digital tokens” that can be transferred directly from payer to payee, and are verified by third parties. This “decentralised” CBDC would then function just like physical banknotes and coins, as it can be used directly and transactions can be done anonymously. However, for practical reasons, most research suggests limiting the DLT verification process to selected participants, such as among commercial banks. Furthermore, the central bank could also serve a “notary” role, by auditing transactions and verifying that funds are available.

The other proposed framework would involve private individuals and firms having an account with the central bank, and all transactions between accounts would be validated and processed by the central bank. Under this “centralised” framework, the CBDC could be thought of as an application of a payment system like RENTAS, but to the wider economy. The central bank would play a similar role to commercial banks, which intermediate funds between accounts across its balance sheet.

Given the shift towards “digital” currency, it raises the opportunity to consider whether CBDC should be paid interest at a rate similar to other risk-free assets such as government bonds. If it is not paid interest, CBDC would be analogous to physical cash. This remuneration aspect would have important bearing on how it affects monetary policy, which is described in the next section.

Diagaram 2

E.   Impact on Monetary Policy from the Introduction of CBDC

Some general observations have been made on the potential impact to monetary policy from an introduction of CBDC.

For example, CBDC could unlock central banks’ ability to capture rapid, real time economic surveillance, which would greatly inform monetary policy formulation. This is due to the underlying DLT property that preserves all transactions, and the virtually instant transactions immediately captured by the ledger.

As described earlier, CBDC could function like physical cash and receive no interest payments. In normal times, economic agents would prefer to keep their money in bank deposits as opposed to CBDC given that bank deposits receive interest payments. However, in the tail-risk event of economic instability or a system-wide bank run, CBDC would be another option in addition to cash. It is fully guaranteed by the central bank with no risk of losing its face value and easily stored in large amounts. This easy switch to CBDC would speed up the bank run. The consequent impairment to financial intermediation would directly weaken the efficacy of monetary policy.

On the other hand, researchers propose that CBDC could receive interest payments for the purpose of transmitting monetary policy action directly to economic agents, which increases the efficiency of monetary policy.

Under this modality, economic agents could also switch to CBDC from bank deposits, which could lead to a deposit outflow. This outflow of deposits to CBDC could motivate banks to compete for deposits, which could in turn increase deposit rates and thus also retail lending rates, despite no increase in the policy rate.

Some advanced economies currently have negative policy rates[4], which are typically not transmitted to retail deposit rates. But the CBDC could perhaps be charged a negative interest rate[5], thus efficiently transmitting to the economy the negative policy rate. This would remove the so-called zero-lower bound problem[6]. However, a key caveat is that given that CBDC is expected to only be a complement to cash (see section F), there could still be a limit to how effectively this negative interest rate is transmitted. If a negative interest rate on CBDC was introduced at a large enough magnitude, economic agents could end up choosing to hold physical cash instead of CBDC. A further counter-argument is that negative returns on currency holdings could prove to be unpopular with the public.

Finally, with CBDC, it could be feasible for central banks to implement helicopter money[7] as an additional tool for monetary policy – although whether such a policy tool is warranted or desirable is beyond the scope of this article.

In conclusion, the potential impact on monetary policy from an introduction of CBCD is unclear; and given limited CBDC currently in existence[8], pure conjecture.

F.   Broad Conclusions and Relevance to Malaysia

Research is still nascent

While the potential impact to the transmission of monetary policy is recognised, this needs to be analysed further. This analysis should be balanced with implications in other intersecting areas of central banking, and also wider implications on the economy, commercial banks and economic agents

Cash is still king?

It is quite unlikely that cryptocurrencies would replace cash transactions any time soon. Pioneering work reviewed generally concludes that CBDC, even if introduced in the future, would likely be a complement rather than a substitute to cash and bank deposits.

Technological hurdles need to be considered, as central bank credibility must be priority

Fung and Halaburda (2016) questioned whether “the central bank would have a comparative advantage in issuing a digital currency, given its lack of market and technical expertise”. Conversely, People’s Bank of China and European Central Bank challenged whether the underlying technology is advanced and reliable enough to be applied by central banks[9]. The bedrock of currencies is the trust that people have in the central bank to preserve the value of money. If the technology for CBDC falls short in guaranteeing this (e.g. cyber-security breach), the central bank risks losing its credibility. This is a key risk, in light of recent data thefts and hacking resulting in millions of losses from cryptocurrency exchanges[10]

CBDC must be welfare-enhancing

“Just because [CBDC] is feasible does not mean it is desirable”[11] 

– David Andolfatto, Vice Governor, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

To quote Bank of Canada Deputy Governor Carolyn Wilkins, “If it simply provides another payment mechanism when cash is a viable alternative, there are circumstances under which the well-being of people could be reduced by its introduction”[12]. It is not compelling enough for CBDC to be implemented just because the technology allows for it. The issuance of CBDC must be research-driven and needs-based, with the aim to unambiguously improve the well-being of people.

Each country’s response would be unique

Ultimately, the extent of countries’ response and intervention with regards to digital currency and CBDCs would vary, reflecting the different economic structure, demographics, risk appetite, and institutional capacity and framework[13]



[1] CBDC is also sometimes interchangeably referred to as digital base money, for example in Mersch (2017).

[2] Featured in research by Kumhof and Barrdear (2016), Bordo and Levin (2017), and Fung (2017) among others.

[3] Private digital currencies allow people to transact anonymously, directly and quickly with each other without the need for a trusted third party due to its underlying technology, the distributed ledger technology (DLT). DLT is a distributed database that allows for decentralised bookkeeping (i.e. processing, validation and authentication of transactions). A DLT keeps all history of transactions in a tamper-proof way and makes them publicly available as the current transactions are linked to the chain of all the previous transactions. The DLT is seen to have a potentially wide range of application, from the financial services sector (e.g. settlements) to retail (e.g. loyalty and rewards) and health-care sectors (e.g. data management). See Ketterer and Andrade (2016); Fung and Halaburda (2016); and Monetary Authority of Singapore (2017).

[4]  Japan, Sweden, Switzerland and Denmark.

[5]  This could be done through reducing balances on economic agents’ accounts, or the CBDC not being redeemed at full value (Source: Skingsley (2016)).

[6]  A situation that characterises the difficulty for central banks to change short-term nominal interest rates to below zero to stimulate economic growth. This is because cash, which can be thought of as being remunerated at 0%, can always be held as an alternative to negative interest rate bearing assets.

[7]  The concept of helicopter money was first introduced by Milton Friedman, and is broadly defined as the printing and distributing of money directly to individuals in the economy, in order to boost economic activity.

[8]  Currently, only Ecuador has issued CBDC. See Diagram 1 for details.

[9] Source: Mersch (2017) and Coindesk (Feb 2016), China’s Central Bank Weighing Blockchain Tech for Digital Currency.

[10] New York Times (Aug 2017), Identity Thieves Hijack Cellphone Accounts to Go After Virtual Currency; Fortune (July 2017), One of the Biggest Ethereum and Bitcoin Exchanges Got Hacked.

[11] Source: Andolfatto (2015), Blogpost on Fedcoin: On the Desirability of a Government Cryptocurrency.

[12] Source: Wilkins (2017), Canada explores digital currency: Fintech collaboration vital to unlock promise.

[13] Adapted from Fung and Halaburda (2016), which attributed the level and type of intervention of central banks to different histories, institutional structures and legislative authorities.


References

Andrade and Ketterer  (2016), Digital Central Bank Money and the Unbundling of the Banking Function, Inter-American Development Bank

Barrdear and Kumhoff  (2016; 2017), The Macroeconomics of Central Bank-Issued Digital Currencies, Bank of England

Bordo and Levin (2017), Central Bank Digital Currency and the Future of Monetary Policy

Chapman et. al. (2017), Project Jasper: Are Distributed Wholesale Payment Systems Feasible Yet?, Bank of Canada

Engert and Fung (2017), Central bank digital currency: Motivations and Implications, Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions and Bank of Canada

Fung and Halaburda (2016), CBDCs: A Framework for Assessing Why and How, Bank of Canada

Monetary Authority of Singapore (2017), Project Ubin: SGD on Distributed Ledger

Skingsley (2016), Should the Riksbank issue e-krona?, Sveriges Riksbank


About the author:

Nurjannah Ahmat is an economist and Sabrina Bashir is a senior economist at the Monetary Policy Department, Bank Negara Malaysia.

Views expressed within are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of Bank Negara Malaysia

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s